Publications

La plupart des informations présentées ci-dessous ont été récupérées via RePEc avec l'aimable autorisation de Christian Zimmermann
Universités : sortir de la pauvreté sans privatiserJournal articleRobert Gary-Bobo et Alain Trannoy, Commentaire, Volume 179, Issue 3, pp. 629-638, 2022

Parmi les priorités affichées dans le programme présidentiel d’Emmanuel Macron figurent l’école, la santé, la dépendance, la police, la justice, l’environnement, l’énergie et la défense. L’absence de l’université dans cette liste est a priori étonnante quand on sait que la dotation publique moyenne par étudiant ne cesse de baisser depuis dix ans, en raison notamment de la hausse des effectifs : tous s’accordent sur ce fait objectif. Lucas Chancel et Thomas Piketty estiment que la dotation publique par étudiant a baissé en termes réels de 16 % entre 2012 et 2022. Le site du ministère de l’Enseignement supérieur ne contredit pas ce constat, en indiquant une baisse nominale de 12 % entre 2011 et 2019. La loi de programmation pour la recherche (LPR) prévoit bien des budgets supplémentaires pour la recherche, à hauteur de 500 millions par an sur les dix prochaines années. À l’horizon du quinquennat qui s’ouvre, si les promesses sont tenues, c’est 0,1 point de PIB en plus pour le financement de la recherche. Mais les sommes qui seraient nécessaires pour nous rapprocher de nos compétiteurs étrangers sont d’un autre ordre de grandeur. Rappelons que la France ne consacre que 1,3 % de son PIB à l’enseignement supérieur, alors que les pays anglo-saxons dépassent les 2 %. Il nous manque 17 milliards par an pour seulement espérer égaler l’Angleterre. Avec 10 milliards de plus par an, on pourrait déjà faire beaucoup, mais nous en sommes loin.
À cela on doit sans doute ajouter que l’évolution de la dette publique et le déficit du budget de l’État nous invitent à un pessimisme renforcé au sujet des dotations publiques dont l’Université pourrait disposer à l’avenir…

Murder nature: Weather and violent crime in rural BrazilJournal articlePhoebe W. Ishak, World Development, Volume 157, pp. 105933, 2022

This paper examines the effect of weather shocks on violent crime using disaggregated data from Brazilian municipalities over the period 1991–2015. Employing a distributed lag model that takes into account temporal correlations of weather shocks and spatial correlation of crime rates, I document that adverse weather shocks in the form of droughts lead to a significant increase in violent crime in rural regions. This effect appears to persist beyond the growing season and over the medium run in contrast to the conventional view perceiving weather effects as transitory. To explain this persistence, I show that weather fluctuations are positively associated not only with agriculture yields, but also with the overall economic activity. Moreover, evidence shows the dominance of opportunity cost mechanism reflected in the fluctuations of the earnings especially for the agriculture and unskilled workers, giving credence that it is indeed the income that matters and not the general socio-economic conditions. Other factors such as local government budget capacity, (un)-employment, poverty, inequality, and psychological factors do not seem to explain violent crime rates.

Child Development in Parent-Child InteractionsJournal articleAvner Seror, Journal of Political Economy, Volume 130, Issue 9, pp. 2462-2499, 2022

I present a model of child development that highlights the effect of parent-child interactions on the formation of skills. Through the parent’s affection, the child learns and builds mental representations of the self as loved and competent. These mental representations shape the child’s noncognitive skills and foster learning. I show that this model provides a unifying explanation for well-established evidence on child development. The model also sheds light on how early exposure to media devices can negatively impact skill acquisition. I discuss implications for the design of policies to reduce inequalities in child development.

Individuals’ willingness to provide geospatial global positioning system (GPS) data from their smartphone during the COVID-19 pandemicJournal articleYulin Hswen, Ulrich Nguemdjo, Elad Yom-Tov, Gregory M. Marcus et Bruno Ventelou, Humanities and Social Sciences Communications, Volume 9, Issue 1, pp. 336, 2022

This study aims to evaluate people’s willingness to provide their geospatial global positioning system (GPS) data from their smartphones during the COVID-19 pandemic. Based on the self-determination theory, the addition of monetary incentives to encourage data provision may have an adverse effect on spontaneous donation. Therefore, we tested if a crowding-out effect exists between financial and altruistic motivations. Participants were randomized to different frames of motivational messages regarding the provision of their GPS data based on (1) self-interest, (2) pro-social benefit, and (3) monetary compensation. We also sought to examine the use of a negative versus positive valence in the framing of the different armed messages. 1055 participants were recruited from 41 countries with a mean age of 34 years on Amazon Mechanical Turk (MTurk), an online crowdsourcing platform. Participants living in India or in Brazil were more willing to provide their GPS data compared to those living in the United States. No significant differences were seen between positive and negative valence framing messages. Monetary incentives of $5 significantly increased participants’ willingness to provide GPS data. Half of the participants in the self-interest and pro-social arms agreed to provide their GPS data and almost two-thirds of participants were willing to provide their data in exchange for $5. If participants refused the first framing proposal, they were followed up with a “Vickrey auction” (a sealed-bid second-priced auction, SPSBA). An average of $17 bid was accepted in the self-interest condition to provide their GPS data, and the average “bid” of $21 was for the pro-social benefit experimental condition. These results revealed that a crowding-out effect between intrinsic and extrinsic motivations did not take place in our sample of internet users. Framing and incentivization can be used in combination to influence the acquisition of private GPS smartphone data. Financial incentives can increase data provision to a greater degree with no losses on these intrinsic motivations, to fight the COVID-19 pandemic.

A new regularization of equilibrium problems on Hadamard manifolds: Applications to theories of desiresJournal articleG. C. Bento, J.X. Cruz Neto, Jr. P. A. Soares et Antoine Soubeyran, Annals of Operations Research, Volume 316, Issue 2, pp. 1301-1318, 2022

In this paper, we introduce a new proximal algorithm for equilibrium problems on a genuine Hadamard manifold, using a new regularization term. We first extend recent existence results by considering pseudomonotone bifunctions and a weaker sufficient condition than the coercivity assumption. Then, we consider the convergence of this proximal-like algorithm which can be applied to genuinely Hadamard manifolds and not only to specific ones, as in the recent literature. A striking point is that our new regularization term have a clear interpretation in a recent “variational rationality” approach of human behavior. It represents the resistance to change aspects of such human dynamics driven by motivation to change aspects. This allows us to give an application to the theories of desires, showing how an agent must escape to a succession of temporary traps to be able to reach, at the end, his desires.

Pareto solutions as limits of collective traps: an inexact multiobjective proximal point algorithmJournal articleG. C. Bento, J. X. Cruz Neto, L. V. Meireles et Antoine Soubeyran, Annals of Operations Research, Volume 316, Issue 2, pp. 1425-1443, 2022

In this paper we introduce a definition of approximate Pareto efficient solution as well as a necessary condition for such solutions in the multiobjective setting on Riemannian manifolds. We also propose an inexact proximal point method for nonsmooth multiobjective optimization in the Riemannian context by using the notion of approximate solution. The main convergence result ensures that each cluster point (if any) of any sequence generated by the method is a Pareto critical point. Furthermore, when the problem is convex on a Hadamard manifold, full convergence of the method for a weak Pareto efficient solution is obtained. As an application, we show how a Pareto critical point can be reached as a limit of traps in the context of the variational rationality approach of stay and change human dynamics.

De l’entreprise libérée à l’entreprise libérante. Essai critique et clinique sur les transformations managérialesJournal articleArnaud Lacan et Michel Dalmas, Management & Avenir, Volume 130, Issue 4, pp. 41-63, 2022

L’entreprise libérée est souvent présentée comme une innovation managériale et un modèle organisationnel d’avenir. Pourtant, même si elle est une tentative de réponse intéressante aux problématiques de déplacement des attentes des collaborateurs au travail, il faut s’interroger sur la véritable nature de cette réponse : véritable concept managérial ou appellation acceptée faute de mieux ? Nous formulons dans cet essai d’abord une critique de l’entreprise libérée avant de proposer une révision conceptuelle à l’aide de l’éclairage postmoderne et en introduisant la notion d’entreprise libérante. Nous suggérons ainsi une nouvelle piste en cherchant à repenser les grandes postures managériales. Nous proposons donc de cesser de vouloir « libérer » l’entreprise pour poser les bases de l’entreprise « libérante », en déplaçant notre réflexion sur les salariés. Ce travail de rénovation conceptuelle s’appuie sur une étude exploratoire qualitative menée auprès de managers « libérateurs » dans des organisations qui se sont autoproclamées « entreprises libérées ». Puis nous étendons les conclusions de cette étude à des pistes de postures managériales au service de collaborateurs libérés, nouvelles postures managériales d’autant plus importantes qu’elles se situent désormais dans un monde de travail hybride post-covid.

Do differences in brute luck influence preferences for redistribution in favour of the environment and health?Journal articleOlivier Chanel et Pavitra Paul, Humanities and Social Sciences Communications, Volume 9, Issue 1, pp. 1-9,Art.nr:338, 2022

Redistributive justice is based on the premise that it is unfair for people to be better or worse off relative to others simply because of their fortune or misfortune. It assumes equal opportunities arising from four factors: social circumstances, effort, option luck and brute luck. This paper seeks to investigate how differences in perceived brute luck influence individual preferences for redistribution in favour of two public policies: “health intervention” and “environmental actions”. These policies are viewed somewhat differently: the environment is considered a pure “public good” and health, more as a “private good” with a strong public good element. Consequently, potential self-serving biases inherent in the preferences for redistributive policies are expected to differ, more likely favouring health than the environment. The perceived degree of brute luck may capture such a difference—those perceiving themselves as luckiest should be less amenable to redistribution in favour of health than the unluckiest. Data from the three waves (2000, 2006 and 2008) of a French population survey are used to examine this self-serving bias. A Generalised Ordered Logit (GOL) model is found to be statistically more relevant compared to other logistic regression models (multinomial and ordered). We find that a perceived low degree of brute luck is significantly associated with a decreased preference of redistributive environmental policies but the reverse is true for redistributive health policies, i.e., association with an increased preference. Assuming that all inequalities due to differing luck are unjust, this empirical validation gives redistributive justice grounds for equalisation policies regarding health.

Estimating willingness to pay for public health insurance while accounting for protest responses: A further step towards universal health coverage in Tunisia?Journal articleMohammad Abu-Zaineh, Olivier Chanel et Khaled Makhloufi, The International Journal of Health Planning and Management, Volume 37, Issue 5, pp. 2809-2821, 2022

Introduction:
Developing countries face major challenges in implementing universal health coverage (UHC): a widespread informal sector, general discontent with rising economic insecurity and inequality and the rollback of state and public welfare. Under such conditions, estimating the demand for a health insurance scheme (HIS) on voluntary basis can be of interest to accelerate the progress of UHC-oriented reforms. However, a major challenge that needs to be addressed in such context is related to protest attitudes that may reflect, inter alia, a null valuation of the expected utility or unexpressed demand.
Methods:
We propose to tackle this by applying a contingent valuation survey to a non-healthcare-covered Tunisian sample vis-à-vis joining and paying for a formal HIS. Our design pays particular attention to identifying the nature of the willingness-to-pay (WTP) values obtained, distinguishing genuine null values from protest values. To correct for potential selection issues arising from protest answers, we estimate an ordered-Probit-selection model and compare it with the standard Tobit and Heckman sample selection models.
Results:
Our results support the presence of self-selection and, by predicting protesters' WTP, allow the “true” sample mean WTP to be computed. This appears to be about 14% higher than the elicited mean WTP.
Conclusion:
The WTP of the poorest non-covered respondents represents about one and a half times the current contributions of the poorest formal sector enrolees, suggesting that voluntary participation in the formal HIS is feasible.

Nowcasting world GDP growth with high-frequency dataJournal articleCaroline Jardet et Baptiste Meunier, Journal of Forecasting, Volume 41, Issue 6, pp. 1181-1200, 2022

Although the Covid-19 crisis has shown how high-frequency data can help track the economy in real time, we investigate whether it can improve the nowcasting accuracy of world GDP growth. To this end, we build a large dataset of 718 monthly and 255 weekly series. Our approach builds on a Factor-Augmented MIxed DAta Sampling (FA-MIDAS), which we extend with a preselection of variables. We find that this preselection markedly enhances performances. This approach also outperforms a LASSO-MIDAS—another technique for dimension reduction in a mixed-frequency setting. Though we find that a FA-MIDAS with weekly data outperform other models relying on monthly or quarterly data, we also point to asymmetries. Models with weekly data have indeed performances similar to other models during “normal” times but can strongly outperform them during “crisis” episodes, above all the Covid-19 period. Finally, we build a nowcasting model for world GDP annual growth incorporating weekly data that give timely (one per week) and accurate forecasts (close to IMF and OECD projections but with 1- to 3-month lead). Policy-wise, this can provide an alternative benchmark for world GDP growth during crisis episodes when sudden swings in the economy make usual benchmark projections (IMF's or OECD's) quickly outdated.